home *** CD-ROM | disk | FTP | other *** search
Text File | 1990-06-24 | 60.0 KB | 1,061 lines |
- Subject: 87-2048--OPINION, TEXACO INC. v. HASBROUCK
-
-
-
-
- NOTICE: This opinion is subject to formal revision before publication in
- the preliminary print of the United States Reports. Readers are requested
- to notify the Reporter of Decisions, Supreme Court of the United States,
- Washington, D. C. 20543, of any typographical or other formal errors, in
- order that corrections may be made before the preliminary print goes to
- press.
- SUPREME COURT OF THE UNITED STATES
-
-
- No. 87-2048
-
-
-
- TEXACO INC., PETITIONER v. RICKY HASBROUCK, dba RICK'S TEXACO, et al.
-
- on writ of certiorari to the united states court of appeals for the ninth
- circuit
-
- [June 14, 1990]
-
-
-
- Justice Stevens delivered the opinion of the Court.
-
- Petitioner (Texaco) sold gasoline directly to respondents and several
- other retailers in Spokane, Washington, at its retail tank wagon prices
- (RTW) while it granted substantial discounts to two distributors. During
- the period between 1972 and 1981, the stations supplied by the two
- distributors increased their sales volume dramatically, while respondents'
- sales suffered a corresponding decline. Respondents filed an action
- against Texaco under the Robinson-Patman Amendment to the Clayton Act
- (Act), 38 Stat. 730, as amended, 49 Stat. 1526, 15 U. S. C. 13, alleging
- that the distributor discounts violated 2(a) of the Act, 15 U. S. C. 13(a).
- Respondents recovered treble damages, and the Court of Appeals for the
- Ninth Circuit affirmed the judgment. We granted certiorari, 490 U. S.
- (1989), to consider Texaco's contention that legitimate functional
- discounts do not violate the Act because a seller is not responsible for
- its customers' independent resale pricing decisions. While we agree with
- the basic thrust of Texaco's argument, we conclude that in this case it is
- foreclosed by the facts of record.
-
- I
-
-
- Given the jury's general verdict in favor of respondents, disputed
- questions of fact have been resolved in their favor. There seems,
- moreover, to be no serious doubt about the character of the market,
- Texaco's pricing practices, or the relative importance of Texaco's direct
- sales to retailers ("through put" business) and its sales to distributors.
- The principal disputes at trial related to questions of causation and
- damages.
-
- Respondents are 12 independent Texaco retailers. They displayed the
- Texaco trademark, accepted Texaco credit cards, and bought their gasoline
- products directly from Texaco. Texaco delivered the gasoline to
- respondents' stations.
-
- The retail gasoline market in Spokane was highly competitive throughout
- the damages period, which ran from 1972 to 1981. Stations marketing the
- nationally advertised Texaco gasoline competed with other major brands as
- well as with stations featuring independent brands. Moreover, although
- discounted prices at a nearby Texaco station would have the most obvious
- impact on a respondent's trade, the cross-city traffic patterns and
- relatively small size of Spokane produced a city-wide competitive market.
- See, e. g., App. 244, 283- 291. Texaco's through put sales in the Spokane
- market declined from a monthly volume of 569,269 gallons in 1970 to 389,557
- gallons in 1975. Id., at 487-488. Texaco's independent retailers' share
- of the market for Texaco gas declined from 76% to 49%. {1} Ibid. Seven of
- the respondents' stations were out of business by the end of 1978. Id., at
- 22-23, R. 501.
-
- The respondents tried unsuccessfully to increase their ability to
- compete with lower priced stations. Some tried converting from full
- service to self-service stations. See, e. g., App. 55-56. Two of the
- respondents sought to buy their own tank trucks and haul their gasoline
- from Texaco's supply point, but Texaco vetoed that proposal. Id., at
- 38-41, 59.
-
- While the independent retailers struggled, two Spokane gasoline
- distributors supplied by Texaco prospered. Gull Oil Company (Gull) had its
- headquarters in Seattle and distributed petroleum products in four western
- States under its own name. Id., at 94-95. In Spokane it purchased its gas
- from Texaco at prices that ranged from six to four cents below Texaco's RTW
- price. Id., at 31-32. Gull resold that product under its own name; the
- fact that it was being supplied by Texaco was not known by either the
- public or the respondents. See, e. g., id., at 256. In Spokane, Gull
- supplied about 15 stations; some were "consignment stations" and some were
- "commission stations." In both situations Gull retained title to the
- gasoline until it was pumped into a motorist's tank. In the consignment
- stations, the station operator set the retail prices, but in the commission
- stations Gull set the prices and paid the operator a commission. Its
- policy was to price its gasoline at a penny less than the prevailing price
- for major brands. Gull employed two truck drivers in Spokane who picked up
- product at Texaco's bulk plant and delivered it to the Gull stations. It
- also employed one supervisor in Spokane. Apart from its trucks and
- investment in retail facilities, Gull apparently owned no assets in that
- market. App. 96-109, 504-512. At least with respect to the commission
- stations, Gull is fairly characterized as a retailer of gasoline throughout
- the relevant period.
-
- The Dompier Oil Company (Dompier) started business in 1954 selling
- Quaker State Motor Oil. In 1960 it became a full line distributor of
- Texaco products, and by the mid-1970's its sales of gasoline represented
- over three-quarters of its business. App. 114-115. Dompier purchased
- Texaco gasoline at prices of 3.95 to 3.65 below the RTW price. Dompier
- thus paid a higher price than Gull, but Dompier, unlike Gull, resold its
- gas under the Texaco brand names. Id., at 24, 29-30. It supplied about
- eight to ten Spokane retail stations. In the period prior to October 1974,
- two of those stations were owned by the president of Dompier but the others
- were independently operated. See, e. g., id., at 119- 121, 147-148. In
- the early 1970's, Texaco representatives encouraged Dompier to enter the
- retail business directly, and in 1974 and 1975 it acquired four stations.
- {2} Id., at 114-135, 483-503. Dompier's president estimated at trial that
- the share of its total gasoline sales made at retail during the middle
- 1970's was "probably 84 to 90 percent." Id., at 115.
-
- Like Gull, Dompier picked up Texaco's product at the Texaco bulk plant
- and delivered directly to retail outlets. Unlike Gull, Dompier owned a
- bulk storage facility, but it was seldom used because its capacity was less
- than that of many retail stations. Again unlike Gull, Dompier received
- from Texaco the equivalent of the common carrier rate for delivering the
- gasoline product to the retail outlets. Thus, in addition to its discount
- from the RTW price, Dompier made a profit on its hauling function. {3}
- App. 123-131, 186-192, 411-413.
-
- The stations supplied by Dompier regularly sold at retail at lower
- prices than respondents'. Even before Dompier directly entered the retail
- business in 1974, its customers were selling to consumers at prices barely
- above the RTW price. Id., at 329-338; Record 315, 1250-1251. Dompier's
- sales volume increased continuously and substantially throughout the
- relevant period. Between 1970 and 1975 its monthly sales volume increased
- from 155,152 gallons to 462,956 gallons; this represented an increase from
- 20.7% to almost 50% of Texaco's sales in Spokane. App. 487-488.
-
- There was ample evidence that Texaco executives were well aware of
- Dompier's dramatic growth and believed that it was attributable to "the
- magnitude of the distributor discount and the hauling allowance." {4} See
- also, e. g., App. 213-223, 407-413. In response to complaints from
- individual respondents about Dompier's aggressive pricing, however, Texaco
- representatives professed that they "couldn't understand it." Record
- 401-404.
-
- II
-
-
- Respondents filed suit against Texaco in July 1976. After a four week
- trial, the jury awarded damages measured by the difference between the RTW
- price and the price paid by Dompier. As we subsequently decided in J.
- Truett Payne Co. v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U. S. 557 (1981), this
- measure of damages was improper. Accordingly, although it rejected
- Texaco's defenses on the issue of liability, {5} the Court of Appeals for
- the Ninth Circuit remanded the case for a new trial. Hasbrouck v. Texaco,
- Inc., 663 F. 2d 930 (1981), cert. denied, 459 U. S. 828 (1982).
-
- At the second trial, Texaco contended that the special prices to Gull
- and Dompier were justified by cost savings, {6} were the product of a good
- faith attempt to meet competition, {7} and were lawful "functional
- discounts." The District Court withheld the cost justification defense
- from the jury because it was not supported by the evidence and the jury
- rejected the other defenses. It awarded respondents actual damages of
- $449,900. {8} The jury apparently credited the testimony of respondents'
- expert witness who had estimated what the respondents' profits would have
- been if they had paid the same prices as the four stations owned by
- Dompier. See 634 F. Supp. 34, 43; 842 F. 2d, at 1043-1044.
-
- In Texaco's motion for judgment notwithstanding the verdict, it claimed
- as a matter of law that its functional discounts did not adversely affect
- competition within the meaning of the Act because any injury to respondents
- was attributable to decisions made independently by Dompier. The District
- Court denied the motion. In an opinion supplementing its oral ruling
- denying Texaco's motion for a directed verdict, the Court assumed,
- arguendo, that Dompier was entitled to a functional discount, even on the
- gas that was sold at retail, {9} but nevertheless concluded that the
- "presumed legality of functional discounts" had been rebutted by evidence
- that the amount of the discounts to Gull and Dompier was not reasonably
- related to the cost of any function that they performed. {10} 634 F.
- Supp., at 37-38, and n. 4.
-
- The Court of Appeals affirmed. It reasoned:
-
- "As the Supreme Court long ago made clear, and recently reaffirmed,
- there may be a Robinson-Patman violation even if the favored and disfavored
- buyers do not compete, so long as the customers of the favored buyer
- compete with the disfavored buyer or its customers. Morton Salt, 334 U. S.
- at 43-44 . . . ; Perkins v. Standard Oil Co., 395 U. S. 642, 646-47 . . .
- (1969); Falls City Indus., Inc. v. Vanco Beverages, Inc., 460 U. S. 428,
- 434-35 (1983). Despite the fact that Dompier and Gull, at least in their
- capacities as wholesalers, did not compete directly with Hasbrouck, a
- section 2(a) violation may occur if (1) the discount they received was not
- cost- based and (2) all or a portion of it was passed on by them to
- customers of theirs who competed with Hasbrouck. Morton Salt, 334 U. S. at
- 43-44, . . . ; Perkins v. Standard Oil, 395 U. S. at 648-49, . . . ; see 3
- E. Kintner & J. Bauer, supra, 22.14.
-
- "Hasbrouck presented ample evidence to demonstrate that . . . . the
- services performed by Gull and Dompier were insubstantial and did not
- justify the functional discount." 842 F. 2d, at 1039.
-
-
- The Court of Appeals concluded its analysis by observing:
-
- "To hold that price discrimination between a wholesaler and a retailer
- could never violate the Robinson-Patman Act would leave immune from
- antitrust scrutiny a discriminatory pricing procedure that can effectively
- serve to harm competition. We think such a result would be contrary to the
- objectives of the Robinson-Patman Act." Id., at 1040 (emphasis in
- original).
-
- III
-
-
- It is appropriate to begin our consideration of the legal status of
- functional discounts {11} by examining the language of the Act. Section
- 2(a) provides in part:
-
-
- "It shall be unlawful for any person engaged in commerce, in the course
- of such commerce, either directly or indirectly, to discriminate in price
- between different purchasers of commodities of like grade and quality,
- where either or any of the purchases involved in such discrimination are in
- commerce, where such commodities are sold for use, consumption, or resale
- within the United States or any Territory thereof or the District of
- Columbia or any insular possession or other place under the jurisdiction of
- the United States, and where the effect of such discrimination may be
- substantially to lessen competition or tend to create a monopoly in any
- line of commerce, or to injure, destroy, or prevent competition with any
- person who either grants or knowingly receives the benefit of such
- discrimination, or with customers of either of them . . . ." 15 U. S. C.
- 13(a).
-
-
- The Act contains no express reference to functional discounts. {12} It
- does contain two affirmative defenses that provide protection for two
- categories of discounts, those that are justified by savings in the
- seller's cost of manufacture, delivery or sale, {13} and those that
- represent a good faith response to the equally low prices of a competitor.
- Standard Oil Co. v. FTC, 340 U. S. 231, 250 (1951). As the case comes to
- us, neither of those defenses is available to Texaco.
-
- In order to establish a violation of the Act, respondents had the
- burden of proving four facts: (1) that Texaco's sales to Gull and Dompier
- were made in interstate commerce; (2) that the gasoline sold to them was of
- the same grade and quality as that sold to respondents; (3) that Texaco
- discriminated in price as between Gull and Dompier on the one hand and
- respondents on the other; and (4) that the discrimination had a prohibited
- effect on competition. 15 U. S. C. 13(a). Moreover, for each respondent
- to recover damages, he had the burden of proving the extent of his actual
- injuries. J. Truett Payne, 451 U. S., at 562.
-
- The first two elements of respondents' case are not disputed in this
- Court, {14} and we do not understand Texaco to be challenging the
- sufficiency of respondents' proof of damages. Texaco does argue, however,
- that although it charged dif- ferent prices, it did not "discriminate in
- price" within the meaning of the Act, and that, at least to the extent that
- Gull and Dompier acted as wholesalers, the price differentials did not
- injure competition. We consider the two arguments separately.
-
- IV
-
-
- Texaco's first argument would create a blanket exemption for all
- functional discounts. Indeed, carried to its logical conclusion, it would
- exempt all price differentials except those given to competing purchasers.
- The primary basis for Texaco's argument is the following comment by
- Congressman Utterback, an active sponsor of the Act:
-
-
- "In its meaning as simple English, a discrimination is more than a mere
- difference. Underlying the meaning of the word is the idea that some
- relationship exists between the parties to the discrimination which enti-
- tles them to equal treatment, whereby the difference granted to one casts
- some burden or disadvantage upon the other. If the two are competing in
- the resale of the goods concerned, that relationship exists. Where, also,
- the price to one is so low as to involve a sacrifice of some part of the
- seller's necessary costs and profit as applied to that business, it leaves
- that deficit inevitably to be made up in higher prices to his other
- customers; and there, too, a relationship may exist upon which to base the
- charge of discrimination. But where no such relationship exists, where the
- goods are sold in different markets and the conditions affecting those
- markets set different price levels for them, the sale to different
- customers at those different prices would not constitute a discrimination
- within the meaning of this bill." 80 Cong. Rec. 9416 (1936).
-
-
- We have previously considered this excerpt from the legislative
- history, and have refused to draw from it the conclusion which Texaco
- proposes. FTC v. Annheuser-Busch, Inc., 363 U. S. 536, 547-551 (1960).
- Although the excerpt does support Texaco's argument, we remain persuaded
- that the argument is foreclosed by the text of the Act itself. In the
- context of a statute that plainly reveals a concern with competitive
- consequences at different levels of distribution, and carefully defines
- specific affirmative defenses, it would be anomalous to assume that the
- Congress intended the term "discriminate" to have such a limited meaning.
- In Annheuser-Busch we rejected an argument identical to Texaco's in the
- context of a claim that a seller's price differential had injured its own
- competitors, a so called "primary line" claim. {15} The reasons we gave
- for our decision in Annheuser-Busch apply here as well. After quoting
- Congressman Utterback's statement in full, we wrote:
-
-
- "The trouble with respondent's arguments is not that they are
- necessarily irrelevant in a 2(a) proceeding, but that they are misdirected
- when the issue under consideration is solely whether there has been a price
- discrimination. We are convinced that, whatever may be said with respect
- to the rest of 2 (a) and 2 (b), and we say nothing here, there are no
- overtones of business buccaneering in the 2(a) phrase `discriminate in
- price.' Rather, a price discrimination within the meaning of that
- provision is merely a price difference." 363 U. S., at 549.
-
-
- After noting that this view was consistent with our precedents, we added:
-
- "the statute itself spells out the conditions which make a price difference
- illegal or legal, and we would derange this integrated statutory scheme
- were we to read other conditions into the law by means of the nondirective
- phrase, `discriminate in price.' Not only would such action be contrary to
- what we conceive to be the meaning of the statute, but, perhaps because of
- this, it would be thoroughly undesirable. As one commentator has
- succinctly put it, "Inevitably every legal controversy over any price
- difference would shift from the detailed governing provisions, "injury,"
- cost justification, "meeting competition," etc., over into the
- "discrimination" concept of ad hoc resolution divorced from specifically
- pertinent statutory text.' Rowe, Price Differentials and Product
- Differentiation: The Issues Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 66 Yale L. J. 1,
- 38." 363 U. S., at 550-551.
-
-
- Since we have already decided that a price discrimination within the
- meaning of 2(a) "is merely a price difference," we must reject Texaco's
- first argument.
-
- V
-
-
- In FTC v. Morton Salt Co., 334 U. S. 37, 46-47 (1948), we held that an
- injury to competition may be inferred from evidence that some purchasers
- had to pay their supplier "substantially more for their goods than their
- competitors had to pay." See also Falls City Industries, Inc. v. Vanco
- Beverage, Inc., 460 U. S. 428, 435-436 (1983). Texaco, supported by the
- United States and the Federal Trade Commission as amici curiae, (the
- Government), argues that this presumption should not apply to differences
- between prices charged to wholesalers and those charged to retailers.
- Moreover, they argue that it would be inconsistent with fundamental
- antitrust policies to construe the Act as requiring a seller to control his
- customers' resale prices. The seller should not be held liable for the
- independent pricing decisions of his customers. As the Government
- correctly notes, Brief for United States et. al. as Amici Curiae 21-22
- (filed Aug. 3, 1989), this argument endorses the position advocated 35
- years ago in the Report of the Attorney General's National Committee to
- Study the Antitrust Laws (1955).
-
- After observing that suppliers ought not to be held liable for the
- independent pricing decisions of their buyers, {16} and that without
- functional discounts distributors might go uncompensated for services they
- performed, {17} the Committee wrote:
-
-
- "The Committee recommends, therefore, that suppliers granting
- functional discounts either to single- function or to integrated buyers
- should not be held responsible for any consequences of their customers'
- pricing tactics. Price cutting at the resale level is not in fact, and
- should not be held in law, `the effect of' a differential that merely
- accords due recognition and reimbursement for actual marketing functions.
- The price cutting of a customer who receives this type of differential
- results from his own independent decision to lower price and operate at a
- lower profit margin per unit. The legality or illegality of this price
- cutting must be judged by the usual legal tests. In any event, consequent
- injury or lack of injury should not be the supplier's legal concern.
-
- "On the other hand, the law should tolerate no subterfuge. For
- instance, where a wholesaler-retailer buys only part of his goods as a
- wholesaler, he must not claim a functional discount on all. Only to the
- extent that a buyer actually performs certain functions, assuming all the
- risk, investment, and costs involved, should he legally qualify for a
- functional discount. Hence a distributor should be eligible for a discount
- corresponding to any part of the function he actually performs on that part
- of the goods for which he performs it." Id., at 208.
-
-
- We generally agree with this description of the legal status of
- functional discounts. A supplier need not satisfy the rigorous
- requirements of the cost justification defense in order to prove that a
- particular functional discount is reasonable and accordingly did not cause
- any substantial lessening of competition between a wholesaler's customers
- and the supplier's direct customers. {18} The record in this case,
- however, adequately supports the finding that Texaco violated the Act.
-
- The hypothetical predicate for the Committee's entire discussion of
- functional discounts is a price differential "that merely accords due
- recognition and reimbursement for actual marketing functions." Such a
- discount is not illegal. In this case, however, both the District Court
- and the Court of Appeals concluded that even without viewing the evidence
- in the light most favorable to the respondents, there was no substantial
- evidence indicating that the discounts to Gull and Dompier constituted a
- reasonable reimbursement for the value to Texaco of their actual marketing
- functions. 842 F. 2d, at 1039; 634 F. Supp., at 37, 38. Indeed, Dompier
- was separately compensated for its hauling function, and neither Gull nor
- Dompier maintained any significant storage facilities.
-
- Despite this extraordinary absence of evidence to connect the discount
- to any savings enjoyed by Texaco, Texaco contends that the decision of the
- Court of Appeals cannot be affirmed without departing "from established
- precedent, from practicality, and from Congressional intent." Brief for
- Petitioner 14. {19} This argument assumes that holding suppliers liable
- for a gratuitous functional discount is somehow a novel practice. That
- assumption is flawed.
-
- As we have already observed, the "due recognition and reimbursement"
- concept endorsed in the Attorney General's Committee's study would not
- countenance a functional discount completely untethered to either the
- supplier's savings or the wholesaler's costs. The longstanding principle
- that functional discounts provide no safe harbor from the Act is likewise
- evident from the practice of the Federal Trade Commission, which has, while
- permitting legitimate functional discounts, proceeded against those
- discounts which appeared to be subterfuges to avoid the Act's restrictions.
- See, e. g., In re Sherwin Williams Co., 36 F. T. C. 25, 70-71 (1943)
- (finding a violation of the Act by paint manufacturers who granted
- "functional or special discounts to some of their dealer-distributors on
- the purchases of such dealer-distributors which are resold by such
- dealer-distributors directly to the consumer through their retail
- departments or branch stores wholly owned by them"); In re the Ruberoid
- Co., 46 F. T. C. 379, 386, 5 (1950) (liability appropriate when functional
- designations do not always indicate accurately "the functions actually
- performed by such purchasers"), aff'd, 189 F. 2d 893 (CA2 1951), rev'd on
- rehearing, 191 F. 2d 294, aff'd, 343 U. S. 470 (1952). {20} See also, e.
- g., In re Doubleday & Co., 52 F. T. C. 169, 209 (1955) ("the Commission
- should tolerate no subterfuge. Only to the extent that a buyer actually
- performs certain functions, assuming all the risks and costs involved,
- should he qualify for a compensating discount. The amount of the discount
- should be reasonably related to the expenses assumed by the buyer"); In re
- General Foods Corp., 52 F. T. C. 798, 824-825 (1956) ("a seller is not
- forbidden to sell at different prices to buyers in different functional
- classes and orders have been issued permitting lower prices to one
- functional class as against another, provided that injury to commerce as
- contemplated in the law does not result," but "[t]o hold that the rendering
- of special services ipso facto [creates] a separate functional
- classification would be to read Section 2 (d) out of the Act"); In re Boise
- Cascade Corp., 107 F. T. C. 76, 212, 214-215 (1986) (regardless of whether
- the FTC has judged functional discounts by reference to the supplier's
- savings or the buyer's costs, the FTC has recognized that "functional
- discounts may usually be granted to customers who operate at different
- levels of trade, and thus do not compete with each other, without risk of
- secondary line competitive injury under the Act"), rev'd on other grounds,
- 267 U. S. App. D. C. 124, 837 F. 2d 1127 (1988). {21} Cf. FLM Collision
- Parts, Inc. v. Ford Motor Co., 543 F. 2d 1019, 1027 (CA2 1976) ("We do not
- suggest or imply that, if a manufacturer grants a price discount or
- allowance to its wholesalers (whether or not labelled `incentive'), which
- has the purpose or effect of defeating the objectives of the Act, 2(a)'s
- language may not be construed to defeat it"); C. Edwards, Price
- Discrimination Law 286-348 (1959) (analyzing cases). {22}
-
- Most of these cases involve discounts made questionable because offered
- to "complex types of distributors" whose "functions became scrambled."
- Doubleday & Co., 52 F. T. C., at 208. This fact is predictable:
- manufacturers will more likely be able to effectuate tertiary line price
- discrimination through functional discounts to a secondary line buyer when
- the favored distributor is vertically integrated. Nevertheless, this
- general tendency does not preclude the possibility that a seller may pursue
- a price discrimination strategy despite the absence of any discrete
- mechanism for allocating the favorable price discrepancy between secondary
- and tertiary line recipients. {23}
-
- Indeed, far from constituting a novel basis for liability under the
- Act, the fact pattern here reflects conduct similar to that which gave rise
- to Perkins v. Standard Oil Co of California, 395 U. S. 642 (1969). Perkins
- purchased gas from Standard, and was both a distributor and a retailer. He
- asserted that his retail business had been damaged through two violations
- of the Act by Standard: first, Standard had sold directly to its own
- retailers at a price below that charged to Perkins; and, second, Standard
- had sold to another distributor, Signal, which sold gas to Western Hyway,
- which in turn sold gas to Regal, a retailer in competition with Perkins.
- {24} The question presented was whether the Act, which refers to
- discriminators, purchasers, and their customers, covered injuries to
- competition between purchasers and the customers of customers of
- purchasers. Id., at 646-647. We held that a limitation excluding such
- "fourth level" competition would be "wholly an artificial one." Id., at
- 647. We reasoned that from "Perkins' point of view, the competitive harm
- done him by Standard is certainly no less because of the presence of an
- additional link in this particular distribution chain from the producer to
- the retailer." {25} The same may justly be said in this case. The
- additional link in the distribution chain does not insulate Texaco from
- liability if Texaco's excessive discount otherwise violated the Act. {26}
-
- Nor should any reader of the commentary on functional discounts be much
- surprised by today's result. Commentators have disagreed about the extent
- to which functional discounts are generally or presumptively allowable
- under the Robinson-Patman Act. They nevertheless tend to agree that in
- exceptional cases what is nominally a functional discount may be an
- unjustifiable price discrimination entirely within the coverage of the Act.
- {27} Others, like Frederick Rowe, have asserted the legitimacy of
- functional discounts in more sweeping terms, {28} but even Rowe concedes
- the existence of an "exception to the general rule." F. Rowe, Price
- Discrimination Under the Robinson-Patman Act 174, n. 7 (1962); id., at
- 195-205. {29}
-
- We conclude that the commentators' analysis, like the reasoning in
- Perkins and like the Federal Trade Commission's practice, renders
- implausible Texaco's contention that holding it liable here involves some
- departure from established understandings. Perhaps respondents' case
- against Texaco rests more squarely than do most functional discount cases
- upon direct evidence of the seller's intent to pass a price advantage
- through an intermediary. This difference, however, hardly cuts in Texaco's
- favor. In any event, the evidence produced by respondents also shows the
- scrambled functions which have more frequently signaled the illegitimacy
- under the Act of what is alleged to be a permissible functional discount.
- Both Gull and Dompier received the full discount on all their purchases
- even though most of their volume was resold directly to consumers. The
- extra margin on those sales obviously enabled them to price aggressively in
- both their retail and their wholesale marketing. To the extent that
- Dompier and Gull competed with respondents in the retail market, the
- presumption of adverse effect on competition recognized in the Morton Salt
- case becomes all the more appropriate. Their competitive advantage in that
- market also constitutes evidence tending to rebut any presumption of
- legality that would otherwise apply to their wholesale sales.
-
- The evidence indicates, moreover, that Texaco affirmatively encouraged
- Dompier to expand its retail business and that Texaco was fully informed
- about the persistent and marketwide consequences of its own pricing
- policies. Indeed, its own executives recognized that the dramatic impact
- on the market was almost entirely attributable to the magnitude of the
- distributor discount and the hauling allowance. Yet at the same time that
- Texaco was encouraging Dompier to integrate downward, and supplying Dompier
- with a generous discount useful to such integration, Texaco was inhibiting
- upward integration by the respondents: two of the respondents sought
- permission from Texaco to haul their own fuel using their own tankwagons,
- but Texaco refused. The special facts of this case thus make it peculiarly
- difficult for Texaco to claim that it is being held liable for the
- independent pricing decisions of Gull or Dompier.
-
- As we recognized in Falls City Industries, "the competitive injury
- component of a Robinson-Patman Act violation is not limited to the injury
- to competition between the favored and the disfavored purchaser; it also
- encompasses the injury to competition between their customers." 460 U. S.,
- at 436. This conclusion is compelled by the statutory language, which
- specifically encompasses not only the adverse effect of price
- discrimination on persons who either grant or knowingly receive the benefit
- of such discrimination, but also on "customers of either of them." Such
- indirect competitive effects surely may not be presumed automatically in
- every functional discount setting, and, indeed, one would expect that most
- functional discounts will be legitimate discounts which do not cause harm
- to competition. At the least, a functional discount that constitutes a
- reasonable reimbursement for the purchasers' actual marketing functions
- will not violate the Act. When a functional discount is legitimate, the
- inference of injury to competition recognized in the Morton Salt case will
- simply not arise. Yet it is also true that not every functional discount
- is entitled to a judgment of legitimacy, and that it will sometimes be
- possible to produce evidence showing that a particular functional discount
- caused a price discrimination of the sort the Act prohibits. When such
- anticompetitive effects are proved, as we believe they were in this case,
- they are covered by the Act. {30}
-
- VI
-
-
- At the trial respondents introduced evidence describing the diversion
- of their customers to specific stations supplied by Dompier. Respondents'
- expert testimony on damages also focused on the diversion of trade to
- specific Dompier- supplied stations. The expert testimony analyzed the
- entire damages period, which ran from 1972 and 1981 and included a period
- prior to 1974 when Dompier did not own any retail stations (although the
- jury might reasonably have found that Dompier controlled the Red Carpet
- stations from the outset of the damages period). Moreover, respondents
- offered no direct testimony of any diversion to Gull and testified that
- they did not even know that Gull was being supplied by Texaco. Texaco
- contends that by basing the damages award upon an extrapolation from data
- applicable to Dompier- supplied stations, respondents necessarily based the
- award upon the consequences of pricing decisions made by independent
- customers of Dompier. Texaco argues that the damages award must therefore
- be judged excessive as a matter of law.
-
- Even if we were to agree with Texaco that Dompier was not a retailer
- throughout the damages period, we could not accept Texaco's argument.
- Texaco's theory improperly blurs the distinction between the liability and
- the damages issues. The proof established that Texaco's lower prices to
- Gull and Dompier were discriminatory throughout the entire nine-year
- period; that at least Gull, and apparently Dompier as well, was selling at
- retail during that entire period; that the discounts substantially affected
- competition throughout the entire market; and that they injured each of the
- respondents. There is no doubt that respondents' proof of a continuing
- violation of the Act throughout the nine-year period was sufficient. Proof
- of the specific amount of their damages was necessarily less precise. Even
- if some portion of some of respondents' injuries may be attributable to the
- conduct of independent retailers, the expert testimony nevertheless
- provided a sufficient basis for an acceptable estimate of the amount of
- damages. We have held that a plaintiff may not recover damages merely by
- showing a violation of the Act; rather, the plaintiff must also "make some
- showing of actual injury attributable to something the antitrust laws were
- designed to prevent. Perkins v. Standard Oil Co., 395 U. S. 642, 648
- (1969) (plaintiff `must, of course, be able to show a causal connection
- between the price discrimination in violation of the Act and the injury
- suffered')." J. Truett Payne v. Chrysler Motors Corp., 451 U. S., at 562.
- At the same time, however, we reaffirmed our "traditional rule excusing
- antitrust plaintiffs from an unduly rigorous standard of proving antitrust
- injury." Id., at 565. See also Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research,
- Inc., 395 U. S. 100, 123-124 (1969); Bigelow v. RKO Radio Pictures, Inc.,
- 327 U. S. 251, 264-265 (1946). {31} Moreover, as we have noted, Texaco did
- not object to the instructions to the jury on the damages issue. A
- possible flaw in the jury's calculation of the amount of damages would not
- be an appropriate basis for granting Texaco's motion for a judgment
- notwithstanding the verdict.
-
- The judgment is affirmed.
-
- It is so ordered.
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
-
- ------------------------------------------------------------------------------
- 1
- The independent retailers' share includes not only the market share for
- the 12 respondents, who operated a total of 13 stations, but also the share
- of some independent Texaco retailers who are not parties to this action.
- Texaco had 27 independent dealers in the Spokane market in 1970, and 19 in
- 1975. App. 22, 487-488.
-
- 2
- "Q. Did you have any conversations with Texaco during this period of
- time encouraging you to, Dompier Oil Company to change its emphasis and to
- move into the retail business? A. Yes, we did.
-
- "Q. Would you tell the jury about that? [A.] Well, at various times
- Texaco encouraged us to begin supplying retail service stations. In the
- early Seventies they did that, and then as time went on, they encouraged us
- to own the stations that we were supplying; in other words, to try to
- control our own retail business. And beginning about 1974, we did purchase
- a station in '74 and some more in '75 and we began operating those as
- company operations with salaried company employees." App. 116-117.
-
- 3
- "Q. That would have been a rate, that if you had hired a common carrier
- to haul the product for you, you would have paid them to haul it? A.
- That's right.
-
- "Q. And do you understand, to your understanding does that common carrier
- rate have a built-in-profit? A. I am sure it does.
-
- "Q. Did you find it to be an advantage to you to be hauling your own
- product? A. Yes." Id., at 126.
-
- 4
- At trial one of Texaco's defenses was based on its obligation to comply
- with certain federal regulations during periods of shortage. In one of its
- communications to the Federal Government, a Texaco vice president wrote, in
- part:
-
- "We believe that the dramatic shift in gasoline sales from the
- independent retailer classes of purchaser to the independent distributor
- classes of purchaser can be explained almost entirely by the magnitude of
- the distributor discount and the hauling allowance." App. 413.
-
- 5
- Texaco had argued that its pricing practices were mandated by federal
- regulations and that its sales in the Spokane market were not "in commerce"
- within the meaning of the Act.
-
- 6
- Section 2(a) of the Act provides, in part:
-
- "That nothing herein contained shall prevent differentials which make only
- due allowance for differences in the cost of manufacture, sale, or delivery
- resulting from the differing methods or quantities in which such
- commodities are to such purchasers sold or delivered."
-
- 7
- Section 2(b) of the Act provides, in part:
-
- "Provided, however, That nothing herein contained shall prevent a seller
- rebutting the prima-facie case thus made by showing that his lower price or
- the furnishing of services or facilities to any purchaser or purchasers was
- made in good faith to meet an equally low price of a competitor, or the
- services or facilities furnished by a competitor."
-
- 8
- The award to each particular respondent of course differed. The awards
- represented an average of $5,486.59 per year for each of the respondents.
-
- 9
- "While there is a serious question as to whether Dompier was entitled
- to a `functional discount' on the gas it resold at retail, compare Mueller
- Co., 60 F. T. C. 120 (1962), aff'd, 323 F. 2d 44 (7th Cir. 1963), cert.
- denied, 377 U. S. 923 . . . (1964) (entitlement to functional discount
- based on resale level) with Doubleday and Co., 52 F. T. C. 169 (1955)
- (entitlement to functional discount based on level of purchase), the court
- assumes, arguendo, that the mere fact that Dompier retailed the gas does
- not preclude a `functional discount."' 634 F. Supp. 34, 37, n. 4 (ED Wash.
- 1985) (emphasis in original).
-
- 10
- "Secondly, the functional discounts negatively affected competition
- because they were, in part, reflected in the favored purchasers' (or their
- customers') retail prices. In other words, the discount was not consumed
- or absorbed at the level of the favored buyers; rather, the amount of the
- discount (or a significant portion) appeared in the favored purchasers'
- retail price, or in the favored purchasers' price to their customers and in
- their customers' retail prices. Under such circumstances, the otherwise
- innocuous nature and presumed legality of functional discounts is rebutted,
- for it is universally recognized that a functional discount remains legal
- only to the extent it acts as compensation for the functions performed by
- the favored buyer. See 3 Kintner & Bauer, Federal Antitrust Law 309-10
- (1983); Rill, Availability and Functional Discounts Justifying
- Discriminatory Pricing, 53 Antitrust L. J. 929, 939-41 (1985). The
- discount must `be reasonably related to the expenses assumed by the
- [favored] buyer' and the discount `should not exceed the cost of . . . the
- function [the favored buyer] actually performs . . . ' Doubleday and
- Company, 52 F. T. C. at 209, cited in Boise Cascade Corp., Docket No. 9133,
- slip op. at 117 (Feb. 14, 1984) (initial decision). If the discount
- exceeds such costs, it cannot be justified as a functional discount,
- particularly where, as here, the excess has a negative effect on
- competition.
- "In this case Texaco made no serious attempt to quantitatively justify
- its functional discounts. While a precise accounting of the value of the
- performed functions is not mandated, merely identifying some of the
- functions is not sufficient. There is no substantial evidence to support
- Texaco's position that the discounts were justified." 634 F. Supp., at 38
- (footnote omitted).
-
- 11
- In their brief filed as amici curiae, the United States and the Federal
- Trade Commission suggest the following definition of "functional discount,"
- which is adequate for our discussion: "A functional discount is one given
- to a purchaser based on its role in the supplier's distributive system,
- reflecting, at least in a generalized sense, the services performed by the
- purchaser for the supplier." Brief for United States et al. as Amici
- Curiae 10 (filed Aug. 3, 1989).
-
- 12
- The legislative history indicates that earlier drafts of the Act did
- include such a proviso. See, e. g., Shniderman, "The Tyranny of Labels", A
- Study of Functional Discounts Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 60 Harv. L.
- Rev. 571, 583-586, and nn. 40-57 (1947). The deletion of this exception
- for functional discounts has ambiguous significance. It may be, as one
- commentator has suggested, that the circumstances of the Act's passage
- "must have conveyed to the congressional mind the realization that the
- judiciary and the FTC would view what had occurred as a narrowing of the
- gates through which the functional classification plan of a seller had to
- pass to come within the law." Id., at 588. In any event, the deletion in
- no way detracts from the blunt direction of the statutory text, which
- indicates that any price discrimination substantially lessening competition
- will expose the discriminator to liability, regardless of whether the
- discriminator attempts to characterize the pricing scheme as a functional
- discount.
-
- 13
- See n. 6, supra.
-
- 14
- Texaco has not contested here the proposition that branded gas and
- unbranded gas are of like grade and quality. See FTC v. Borden Co., 383 U.
- S. 637, 645-646 (1966) ("the economic factors inherent in brand names and
- national advertising should not be considered in the jurisdictional inquiry
- under the statutory `like grade and quality' test").
-
- 15
- It has proven useful in Robinson-Patman Act cases to distinguish among
- "the probable impact of the [price] discrimination on competitors of the
- seller (primary-line injury), on the favored and disfavored buyers
- (second-line injury), or on the customers of either of them (third-line
- injury)." See 3 E. Kintner & J. Bauer, Federal Antitrust Law 20.9 p. 127
- (1983).
-
- 16
- "In the Committte's view, imposing on any dual supplier a legal
- responsibility for the resale policies and prices of his independent
- distributors contradicts basic antitrust policies. Resale-price fixing is
- incompatible with the tenets of a free and competitive economy. What is
- more, the arrangements necessary for policing, detecting, and reporting
- price cuttters may be illegal even apart from the resale-price agreement
- itself. And even short of such arrangements, a conscious adherence in a
- supplier's sales to retail customers to the price quotations by independent
- competing distributors is hardly feasible as a matter of business
- operation, or safe as a matter of law." Report of the Attorney General's
- National Committee to Study the Antitrust Laws 206-207 (1955) (footnores
- omitted).
-
- 17
- "In our view, to relate discounts or prices solely to the purchaser's
- resale activities without recognition of his buying functions thwarts
- competition and efficiency in marketing. It compels affirmative
- discrimination against a substantial class of distributors, and hence
- serves as a penalty on integration. If a businessman actually fulfills the
- wholesale function by relieving his suppliers of risk, storage,
- transportation, administration, etc., his performance, his capital
- investment, and the saving to his suppliers, are unaffected by whether he
- also performs the retailing function, or any number of other functions. A
- legal rule disqualifying him from discounts recognizing wholesaling
- functions actually performed compels him to render these functions free of
- charge." Id., at 207.
-
- 18
- In theory, a supplier could try to defend a functional discount by
- invoking the Act's cost justification defense, but the burden of proof with
- respect to the defense is upon the supplier, and interposing the defense
- "has proven difficult, expensive, and often unsuccessful." 3 E. Kintner &
- J. Bauer, Federal Antitrust Law, 23.19, pp. 366-367 (1983). Moreover, to
- establish the defense a "seller must show that the price reductions given
- did not exceed the actual cost savings," id., 23.10, p. 345, and this
- requirement of exactitude is ill-suited to the defense of discounts set by
- reference to legitimate, but less precisely measured, market factors. Cf.
- Calvani, Functional Discounts Under the Robinson-Patman Act, 17 B. C. Ind.
- & Com. L. Rev. 543, 546, n. 16 (1976) (distinguishing functional discounts
- from cost-justified price differences); Report of the Attorney General's
- National Commmittee on the Antitrust Laws, at 171 ("the cost defense has
- proved largely illusory in practice").
- Discounters will therefore likely find it more useful to defend against
- claims under the Act by negating the causation element in the case against
- them: a legitimate functional discount will not cause any substantial
- lessening of competition. The concept of substantiality permits the
- causation inquiry to accommodate a notion of economic reasonableness with
- respect to the pass-through effects of functional discounts, and so
- provides a latitude denied by the cost-justification defense. Cf.
- Shniderman, 60 Harv. L. Rev., at 603-604 (substantiality defense in
- functional discount cases). We thus find ourselves in substantial
- agreement with the view that:
-
- "Conceived as a vehicle for allowing differential pricing to reward
- distributive efficiencies among customers operating at the same level, the
- cost justification defense focuses on narrowly defined savings to the
- seller derived from the different method or quantities in which goods are
- sold or delivered to different buyers. . . . Moreover, the burden of proof
- as to the cost justification defense is on the seller charged with
- violating the Act, whereas the burden of proof remains with the enforcement
- agency or plaintiff in circumstances involving functional discounts since
- functional pricing negates the probability of competitive injury, an
- element of a prima facie case of violation." Rill, Availability and
- Functional Discounts Justifying Discriminatory Pricing, 53 Antitrust L. J.
- 929, 935 (1985) (footnotes omitted).
-
- 19
- Texaco continues the argument by summoning a parade of horribles whose
- march Texaco believes is at issue in this case: according to Texaco, the
- Court of Appeals' rule "would multiply distribution costs, rigidify and
- increase consumer prices, encourage resale price maintenance in violation
- of the Sherman Act, . . . , and jeopardize the businesses of wholesalers."
- Brief for Petitioner 14.
-
- 20
- See also, e. g., In re Whiting, 26 F. T. C. 312, 316, 3 (1938)
- (functional classification of customers involved unlawful price
- discrimination because of functional overlap); In re Standard Oil Co., 41
- F. T. C. 263 (1945), modified and aff'd, 173 F. 2d 210, 217 (CA7 1949)
- ("The petitioner should be liable if it sells to a wholesaler it knows or
- ought to have known . . . is using or intends to use [the wholesaler's]
- price advantage to undersell the petitioner in its prices made to its
- retailers"), rev'd and remanded on other grounds, 340 U. S. 231 (1951).
- In the Standard Oil case, the FTC itself on remand dropped the part of
- its order prohibiting Standard Oil from giving functional discounts. See
- C. Edwards, Price Discrimination Law 309 (1959). The FTC's pre- remand
- theory in the Standard Oil case has of course been the subject of harsh
- criticism. See, e. g., Report of the Attorney General's National Committee
- to Study the Antitrust Laws, at 206. Much, if not all, of this criticism
- rests upon the view that, under the FTC's Standard Oil ruling, a "supplier
- is charged with legal responsibility for the middlemen's pricing tactics,
- and hence must control their resale prices lest they undercut him to the
- unlawful detriment of his directly purchasing retailers. Alternatively,
- the seller may forego his operational freedom by matching his quotations to
- retailers with theirs." Ibid. Nothing in our opinion today should be read
- to condone or approve such a result.
-
- 21
- See also In re Mueller Co., 60 F. T. C. 120, 127-128 (1962) (refusing
- to make allowance for functional discounts in any way that would "add a
- defense to a prima facie violation of Section 2(a) which is not included in
- either Section 2(a) or Section 2(b)"), aff'd, 323 F. 2d 44 (CA7 1963),
- cert. denied, 377 U. S. 923 (1964). The FTC in Mueller expressly disavowed
- dicta from Doubleday suggesting that functional discounts are per se legal
- if justified by the buyer's costs. Mueller held that the discounts were
- controlled instead by the reasoning propounded in General Foods, which
- refers to the value of the services to the supplier giving the discount.
- 60 F. T. C., at 127-128.
- We need not address the relative merits of Mueller and Doubleday in
- order to resolve the case before us. We do, however, reject the
- requirement of exactitude which might be inferred from Doubleday's dictum
- that a functional discount offered to a buyer "should not exceed the cost
- of that part of the function he actually performs on that part of the goods
- for which he performs it." 52 F. T. C., at 209. As already noted, a
- causation defense in a functional discount case does not demand the
- rigorous accounting associated with a cost justification defense.
-
- 22
- The Government's position in this case does not contradict this course
- of decision. The Government's amicus brief on Texaco's behalf criticizes
- the Court of Appeals opinion on the thoery that it "would require a
- supplier to show that a functional discount is justified by the
- wholesaler's costs," and that it imposed "liability for downstream
- competitive effects of legitimate functional discounts." Brief for United
- States et al. as Amici Curiae 16, 6 (filed Aug. 3, 1989). Cf. Boise
- Cascade Corp. v. FTC, 837 F. 2d 1127, 1141-1143 (267 U. S. App. D. C. 124,
- 1988) (summarizing debate about relevance of buyer's costs to defense of
- functional discounts). If the Court of Appeals were indeed to have
- endorsed either of these rules, it would have departed perceptibly from the
- mainstream of the FTC's reading of the Act. We need not decide whether the
- Government's interpretation of the Court of Appeals opinion is correct, for
- we affirm its judgment for reasons that do not entail the principles
- criticized by the Government. Indeed, the Government itself opposed the
- petition for certiorari in this case on the ground that "we do not think
- that this case on its facts presents the broad issue that petitioner
- discusses (whether a supplier must show that its discounts to wholesalers
- relative to retailers are cost based)." Brief for United States as Amicus
- Curiae 12 (filed May 16, 1989).
-
- 23
- The seller may be willing to accept any division of the price
- difference so long as some significant part is passed on to the
- distributor's customers. Although respondents here did not need to show
- any benefit to Texaco from the price discrimination scheme in order to
- establish a violation of the Act, one possibility is indicated by the brief
- filed amicus curiae by the Service Station Dealers of America (SSDA), an
- organization representing both stations supplied by independent jobbers and
- stations supplied directly by sellers. See Brief for SSDA as Amicus Curiae
- 1-2. SSDA suggests that an indirect price discount to competitors may be
- used to force directly supplied franchisees out of the market, and so to
- circumvent federal restrictions upon the termination of franchise
- agreements. See 92 Stat. 324-332, 15 U. S. C. 2801-2806.
- One would expect that, absent a safe harbor rule making functional
- discounts a useful means to engage in otherwise unlawful price
- discrimination, excessive functional discounts of the sort in evidence here
- would be rare. As the Government correctly observes, "[t]his case appears
- to reflect rather anomalous behavior on the part of the supplier." Brief
- for United States et al. as Amici Curiae 17, n. 15 (filed Aug. 3, 1989).
- See also Brief for United States as Amicus Curiae 15 (filed May 16, 1989)
- ("market forces should tend to discourage a supplier from offering
- independent wholesalers discounts that would allow them to undercut the
- supplier's own retail customers").
-
- 24
- Much of Perkins's case parallels that of respondents. "There was
- evidence that Signal received a lower price from Standard than did Perkins,
- that this price advantage was passed on, at least in part, to Regal, and
- that Regal was thereby able to undercut Perkins' price on gasoline.
- Furthermore there was evidence that Perkins repeatedly complained to
- Standard officials that the discriminatory price advantage given Signal was
- being passed down to Regal and evidence that Standard officials were aware
- that Perkins' business was in danger of being destroyed by Standard's
- discriminatory practices. This evidence is sufficient to sustain the
- jury's award of damages under the Robinson-Patman Act." 395 U. S., at
- 649.
-
- 25
- We added: "Here Standard discriminated in price between Perkins and
- Signal, and there was evidence from which the jury could conclude that
- Perkins was harmed competitively when Signal's price advantage was passed
- on to Perkins' retail competitor Regal. These facts are sufficient to give
- rise to recoverable damages under the Robinson-Patman Act." 395 U. S., at
- 648.
-
- 26
- In fact, the principle applied in Perkins, that we will not construe
- the Robinson-Patman Act in a way that "would allow price discriminators to
- avoid the sanctions of the Act by the simple expedient of adding an
- additional link to the distribution chain," 395 U. S., at 647, seems
- capable of governing this case as well. It might be possible to view
- Perkins as standing for a narrower proposition, either because Signal
- apparently exercised majority control over the intermediary, Western Hyway,
- and its retailer, Regal, see id., at 651 (Marshall, J., concurring in part
- and dissenting in part), or because Standard did not assert that its price
- to Signal reflected a "functional discount." However, as the Perkins
- dissent pointed out, ibid., the Perkins majority did not put any such
- limits on the principle it declared.
-
- 27
- See, e. g., Celnicker & Seaman, Functional Discounts, Trade Discounts,
- Economic Price Discrimination and the Robinson-Patman Act, 1989 Utah L.
- Rev. 813, 857 (1989) (concluding that "[t]rade discounts often are
- manifestations of economic price discrimination. . . . If a trade discount
- violates the normal competitive disadvantage criteria used under the Act,
- no special devices should be employed to protect it"); Rill, 53 Antitrust
- L. J., at 940-941 ("Although it is entirely appropriate for the FTC and the
- courts to insist that some substantial services be performed in order for a
- buyer to earn a functional discount, a requirement of precise mathematical
- equivalency makes no sense"); 3 E. Kintner & J. Bauer, Federal Antitrust
- Law 318-320, and n. 305 (1983) ("Functional discounts . . . are usually
- deemed lawful," but this usual rule is subject to exception in cases,
- "arising in unusual circumstances," when the seller's "discrimination
- caused" the tertiary line injury); Calvani, 17 B. C. Ind. & Com. L. Rev.,
- at 549, and n. 26 (1976) (discounts to wholesalers are generally held not
- to injure competition, but this rule is subject to qualifications, and
- "[p]erhaps the most important caveat focuses on the situation where the
- seller sells to both resellers and the consumers and the resellers pass on
- to consumers all or part of the wholesaling functional discount"); C.
- Edwards, Price Discrimination Law 312-313 (1959) ("It is not surprising
- that from time to time the Commission has been unable to avoid finding
- injurious discrimination between direct and indirect customers nor to avoid
- corrective orders that sought to define the gap between prices at
- successive levels of distribution"); Kelley, Functional Discounts Under the
- Robinson-Patman Act, 40 Cal. L. Rev. 526, 556 (1952) (concluding that the
- "characterization of a price differential between two purchasers as a
- functional or trade discount accords it no cloak of immunity from the
- prohibitions of the Robinson-Patman Act"); Shniderman, 60 Harv. L. Rev., at
- 599-600 (Commission's approach to functional discounts "may have been
- influenced by the possibility of subtle price discriminating techniques
- through the employment of wholesalers receiving more than ample discount
- differentials").
- Professor Edwards, among others, describes the status of functional
- discounts under the Robinson-Patman Act with clear dissatisfaction. He
- complains that "The failure of the Congress to cope with the problem . . .
- has left the Commission an impossible job in this type of case." Price
- Discrimination Law, at 313. He adds that the Commission's "occasional
- proceedings" have been attributed to the "Commission's wrong-headedness."
- Id., at 312. Professor Edwards's observations about the merits of the
- statute and about prosecutorial discretion are obviously irrelevant to our
- own inquiry. Unlike scholarly commentators, we have a duty to be faithful
- to congressional intent when interpreting statutes, and are not free to
- consider whether, or how, the statute should be rewritten.
-
- 28
- "In practice, the competitive effects requirement permits a supplier to
- quote different prices between different distributor classes, so long as
- those who are higher up (nearer the supplier) on the distribution ladder
- pay less than those who are further down (nearer the consumer)." F. Rowe,
- Price Discrimination Under the Robinson-Patman Act 174 (1962) (footnote
- omitted); see also id., at 178.
-
- 29
- Rowe, writing prior to this Court's Perkins decision, describes the
- exception, which he identifies with the Standard Oil cases, as "of dubious
- validity today." Id., at 196. Rowe's analysis is flawed because he
- assumes that seller liability for tertiary line implications of wholesaler
- discounts must follow the logic of the Standard Oil complaint, and likewise
- assumes that this logic exposes to liability any seller who fails to
- monitor the resale prices of its wholesaler. Id., at 204. Indeed, Rowe's
- own discussion suggests one defect in his argument: legitimate wholesaler
- discounts will usually be insulated from liability by an absence of
- evidence on the causation issue. Id., at 203-204. In any event, nothing
- in our opinion today endorses a theory of liability under the
- Robinson-Patman Act for functional discounts so broad as the theory Rowe
- draws from Standard Oil.
-
- 30
- The parties do not raise, and we therefore need not address, the
- question whether the inference of injury to competition might also be
- negated by evidence that disfavored buyers could make purchases at a
- reasonable discount from favored buyers.
-
- 31
- In J. Truett Payne, 451 U. S., at 565-566, we quoted with approval the
- following passage:
-
- "[D]amage issues in these cases are rarely susceptible of the kind of
- concrete, detailed proof of injury which is available in other contexts.
- The Court has repeatedly held that in the absence of more precise proof,
- the factfinder may `conclude as a matter of just and reasonable inference
- from the proof of defendants' wrongful acts and their tendency to injure
- plaintiffs' business, and from the evidence of the decline in prices,
- profits and values, not shown to be attributable to other causes, that
- defendants' wrongful acts had caused damage to the plaintiffs.' Bigelow v.
- RKO Pictures, Inc., [327 U. S.], at 264. See also Eastman Kodak Co. v.
- Southern Photo Materials Co., 273 U. S. 359, 377-379 (1927); Story
- Parchment Co. v. Paterson Parchment Paper Co., 282 U. S. 555, 561-566
- (1931)." Zenith Radio Corp. v. Hazeltine Research, Inc., 395 U. S., at
- 123-124.
-